Loading...

Interdisciplinary Public Finance, Business and Economics Studies—Volume VI

by Adil Akinci (Volume editor)
©2023 Edited Collection 490 Pages

Summary

This volume is a collection of empirical and theoretical research papers regarding Economics, Public Finance and Business written by researchers from several different universities. The studies include a wide range of topics from issues in Economics, Public Finance and Business. The book is aimed at educators, researchers, and students interested in Public Finance, Business and Economics.

Table Of Contents

  • Cover
  • Title
  • Copyright
  • About the author
  • About the book
  • This eBook can be cited
  • Contents
  • An Evaluation of Military Expenditures in the Light of Keynesian Thought
  • Robot Tax: Can a Solution to Technological Unemployment?
  • The Historical Development of Accounting in Slovakia: Impact of Automatization on Accounting
  • The Development of Natural Catastrophe Insurances as a Disaster Finance Tool in Turkey
  • The Effect of Financial Risks on the Firm Value of Banks
  • Digital Financial Inclusion in Turkey
  • Portfolio Optimization: An Application on the BIST-30 Index
  • Effects of Uncertainties on the Payment Terms in Türkiye’s Foreign Trade with Central Asian Turkish Republics: Panel Data Analysis
  • Bitcoin and Absolute Purchasing Power Parity Tests in Türkiye
  • Investigating Dynamic Relationship among Remittances, Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth: Case for Emerging Market and Middle-Income Europe
  • Linear and Nonlinear Effects of Climate Policy Uncertainty on Food Inflation: Climate Change or Covid-19?
  • The Effect of Renewable Energy Types on Economic Growth in the USA: Forecasting 2050 with Artifical Neural Networks
  • Time-Varying Causality between Foreign Direct Investment and Environmental Pollution in Emerging Economies
  • Economic Culture and Energy Consumption: Reflections from Turkiye
  • The Return of Inflation and the Supply Chain Pressures
  • Disinflation Phase and Stock Market: The Turkish Case
  • A Review on the Contribution of Aviation Sector on Employment and GDP
  • Fuel Price Risk Management in Airline Transportation
  • The Relation between the Enlightenment and the Dissemination of Political Economy in the Late Ottoman Empire: The Influence of the German Historical School on Ahmed Midhat Efendi’s Economic Thought
  • Integrated Analysis of Quality of Life of Asian Region Countries
  • Africa in the Scope of Türkiye’s Commercial Diplomacy Activities
  • Finding Groups in Data with a Multivariate Statistical Method: A Clustering Analysis Application
  • Perception of Loneliness in Organizational Life
  • Learning Organizations: The Role of Learning and Innovation for the Future
  • Organizational Innovativeness
  • Strategic Brand Management in Enterprises: A Conceptual Review*
  • The Relationship between Organizational Bullying, Intention to Leave and Emotional Contagion
  • Occupational Health and Safety in Hotels: Analysis of Risk Factors
  • Digital Competency Levels of SME Employees
  • Second-Hand Clothing Shopping: A Summary of Shopping Orientations and Shopping Concerns
  • The Impact of Parasocial Interaction on Today’s Purchases
  • The Importance of Experiential Marketing
  • Online Shopping and Consumer Behavior
  • Marketing Communication and Social Media Marketing in the Social Media Era
  • Luxury Consumption Behavior
  • Brand Hate with Causes and Consequences
  • Audit Committee and Its Relation to Market Value
  • Gender-Sensitive Budgeting in Climate Justice
  • Smart Urban Transformation Policies and Practices in Turkey
  • Bioenergy in the Trilogy of Energy Demand, Food Security and Climate Change
  • Gender and Social Reproduction in the Political Economy of Feminism
  • Parliamentary Government System and Political Stability

Metin Doğan1

An Evaluation of Military Expenditures in the Light of Keynesian Thought

1. Introduction

Keynesianism is based on the assumption that an increase in public spending will lead to an increase in aggregate demand through a multiplier effect. Government investments will increase aggregate demand and this will stimulate the economy. This Keynesian idea is widely said to have emerged in the 1930s. Following the 1929 Great Depression, governments resorted to public spending to combat rising unemployment and macroeconomic problems. In this period, infrastructure investments that would create public jobs and public expenditures with strong social aspects such as education and health expenditures were predominantly used. Later, military expenditures were used in the 1940s due to World War II. During this period, unemployment in the United States of America (USA) fell to the lowest levels in history thanks to the production of military equipment and products. These experiences in the 1930s and 1940s led to the identification of Keynesianism as social Keynesianism and military Keynesianism. John Maynard Keynes was aware of the impact of military spending, a component of public spending, on employment. However, Keynes argued that employment should be increased through social expenditures such as infrastructure investments, not military expenditures. Keynes was also aware that international financial policies would lead to violence and war. This is why he argued for a more balanced international economic structure to avoid radical ideas and wars in his various works.

Today, it can be said that the share of military expenditures in gross domestic product (GDP) is on a downward trend compared to World War II. Nevertheless, military expenditures still constitute a significant share of public expenditures. On the other hand, public expenditures on education and health have declined more rapidly since the 1980s. In today’s world of fundamental problems such as the climate crisis and income inequalities, there is a need to re-evaluate military and social expenditures in line with Keynes’s ideas. Military expenditures lead to lower allocations for education, health and other social expenditures and prevent the allocation of sufficient resources to combat environmental problems. Therefore, some authors argue that resources can be allocated to tackling these problems through transfers from military expenditures. This study discusses how public expenditures should be evaluated in combating today’s problems, taking into account the distinction between military and social Keynesianism.

2. A Brief Assessment of Military Expenditures

There are many economic and strategic reasons for resorting to military expenditures as an element of public expenditures. According to the Keynesian approach, keeping public expenditures high will ensure that unused resources in the economy are drawn into economic production and increase total output (Elveren, 2019: 42). Military expenditures are also a part of public expenditures made by the government and help to increase aggregate demand and thus have a positive impact on the economy2 (Dunne, 2013: 113). Wray (2000) divides these positive effects of military expenditures on the economy into two categories: supply-side and demand-side. An increase in military expenditures will increase the number of recruits. This will lead to a reduction in unemployment (the military expenditure-employment relationship has changed due to the absence of frontline wars, the transition to professional military service, and the change in security threats). Another effect is the contribution of technology3 developed through military expenditures to civilian production. Military expenditures will also have the effect of increasing aggregate demand. Aggregate demand4 will stimulate consumer demand as well as the demand for goods and services generated by government spending. Kalecki, on the other hand, considers military spending more efficient than civilian spending. Military expenditures are more advantageous because military expenditures do not take place in business lines where the private sector operates, they redirect unused resources to the private sector and create more employment. In addition, governments can more easily obtain spending authorization for military expenditures and the resulting budget deficits are more bearable (Toporowski, 2016: 439).

After World War II, military expenditures played an important role in increasing aggregate supply and demand and had a positive impact on economic growth. However, this effect will not be observed in the long run due to some limitations. Some technologies developed in the past thanks to military expenditures have also been used in civilian sectors. However, these technological opportunities are limited. The military-industrial complex absorbs well-educated workers and hampers production and technological development in the civilian sector. There is also a distorting effect on the labor market, not only for highly skilled workers but also for low-skilled military personnel (military personnel engaged in hot conflict struggle with various psychological illnesses) (Wray, 2000: 1–2). Criticisms of military spending are not limited to these. Contrary to Kaleckian view, military expenditures are also counted among non-productive public expenditures in some studies. Armament is often understood as a threat of war, which triggers new wars. In addition, the obsolescence of military ammunition leads to new costs in the public budget. Military expenditures also have less social impact. In the short term, the efforts made to prepare for war provide a temporary stimulus for the economy but lead to an increase in the debt burden on the budget (Coulomb & Alcouffe, 2018). Marxist economists have also made important contributions and criticisms on military spending. Terry Caslin (1993) argues that although public expenditures appear to be a pro-labor policy tool, in reality they are used by the authorities for capital accumulation. Especially in times of crisis, public expenditures are used to ensure that capital emerges from the crisis with minimal damage and to harmonize capital with the new economic structure that emerges after the crisis. According to authors such as Luxemburg, Baran and Sweezy, Caslin’s view on public expenditures is more explicit in military expenditures. Military expenditures were seen by these authors as a means of postponing crises, overcoming the problem of low consumption (a perspective close to Keynesians), and ensuring capital accumulation (Dunne, 2013: 119).

3. Keynesianism from the Great Recession to World War II

John Maynard Keynes (2010) published his famous book The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money in 1936. In this book, Keynes argued that public spending should be increased to stimulate aggregate demand and private investment. Keynes’s thinking is often linked to post-Great Depression policies. However, this Keynesian approach can be found in different forms throughout history5. For example, World War I is one of the extraordinary periods in terms of public expenditures. Public expenditures increased significantly in many countries that participated in the war. World War I was also exceptional in terms of state interventions (Nakano, 2021: 4). In another example, Custers notes that economic policies similar to Keynesianism were practiced in Great Britain and other advanced capitalist countries in the 17th and 18th centuries. Increasing aggregate demand through deficit financing or budget deficits, one of the basic principles of Keynesianism, is an example of these Keynesian-like policies (Custers, 2010a: 175).

Despite these examples that emerged in the past, it is accepted that the first mature Keynesian implementation started with the New Deal. The New Deal was implemented in the first term of Roosevelt’s presidency. During this period, in addition to institutional arrangements in the financial and labor markets, investments in physical infrastructure such as roads, schools, parks, hospitals, etc. were made and these investments contributed to economic growth and a rapid increase in employment. Unemployment began to decline rapidly thanks to many pro-labor policies as well as public works. However, a new economic recession began in 1938 (Field, 2009: 99). Although unemployment, which had reached 25 % in 1933, dropped to 14.3 % in 1937, it started to rise again after this post-New Deal recession and reached 19 % in 1938 (Renshaw, 1999). The US government’s adoption of a balanced budget policy was influential in the onset of this recession. This policy decreased the budget deficit to 1.17 billion dollars in 1938. As of 1939, however, the government abandoned the fiscal policy that emphasized budget balance and instead introduced a new fiscal policy in which military expenditures constituted the bulk of public expenditures. From 1942 onwards, public spending exceeded 40 % of GDP (Mauro et al., 2015). The increase of more than 30 % in public expenditures stemmed from the increase in defense-military expenditures due to World War II. These expenditures affected employment and GDP in a short time. The labor market reached almost full employment levels. In 1938, under recessionary conditions, the number of unemployed reached 10.4 million, but by 1944 it had fallen to 600,000. This means that new jobs are created for 18 % of the total workforce. (GDP increased by 52.4 % compared to the 1939 level) (Cypher, 2015: 451). The New Deal described above and the military expenditures made in the post-1939 period are important in terms of Keynesianism. The New Deal plan implemented between 1933 and 1937 is considered to be civilian/social Keynesianism since it had Keynesian features such as state intervention, increase in public expenditures and open budget policy and, as mentioned above, almost all of it consisted of social/civilian expenditures. Military Keynesianism became widespread after 1939, when unemployment decreased and national income increased due to the increase in defense/military expenditures and budget deficits (Custers, 2010a: 176–178).

4. Military Spending and Keynes

Keynes was a writer who emphasized diplomacy, peace and international balance. As a pro-peace diplomat, he also participated in the Treaty of Versailles negotiations in 1919. In these negotiations, Keynes advocated the idea that in order to end violence, the economy should be built on solid foundations and employment and income balance should be ensured (Pattifor, 2019). After World War I, he stated that the economic policies implemented for the rehabilitation of Europe were wrong. He predicted that these policies would lead Europe to totalitarian systems and violence. The outbreak of World War II justified Keynes’s view (Baca, 2021: 6). Keynes’s pro-peace stance was also reflected in his ideas on economics. Keynes’s fiscal policy emphasizes civilian expenditures, not military expenditures. Therefore, he states that large-scale infrastructure investments should be made through public policy and low-interest rates. Keynes has a negative attitude toward military expenditures. Military spending would be a burden on the economy by causing an increase in government debt (Coulomb & Alcouffe, 2018: 12).

Keynes’s opinion on wars is also seen in his open letter to Roosevelt. In this letter, Keynes states that wars always cause intense industrial activity and that the conventional financial establishment sees war as the only legitimate way to create jobs through government spending. Keynes suggested to Roosevelt that public military spending, which until then had only been allowed to serve the purposes of war and destruction, should be replaced by public civilian spending for peace and prosperity (Keynes, 1933). As can be seen in this open letter, Keynes is nevertheless aware of the economic impact of military spending. In other speeches, he stated that war would provide the necessary convenience for governments to engage in large expenditures (Stancl & Hynkova, 2014: 133). Although Keynes did not support government spending on war and armaments, he considered the approach of World War II as an important experiment to see the correctness of his thesis on increasing aggregate demand. If military spending reduced unemployment, Keynes’s ideas would have been vindicated. Preparation for war, according to Keynes, would bring higher living standards and consumption than the New Deal (Barker, 2019: 14). As a result, World War II was an important turning point in terms of the impact of public spending. After the war, there were positive results in terms of economic growth and employment (Stancl & Hynkova, 2014: 134). Military expenditures facilitated the recognition and implementation of Keynesianism (even though Keynes did not approve of it). After World War II, Western states, especially the US, resorted to Keynesian policies in the 1950s and 60s (it was not even called Keynesianism until the 1960s) to prevent financial fluctuations in business life. Keynesianism was also institutionalized in these years, especially in military terms. World War II and the Korean War that followed ensured the purchase of the equipment and systems needed by the American military and stimulated aggregate demand (Custers, 2010a: 175).

In 1965, The Times magazine ran a portrait of Keynes on its cover with the headline “The Economy: We Are All Keynesians Now”, Keynesianism became very popular. By 1971, US President Richard Nixon identified himself as an economic Keynesian (White, 2012: 127). Paul Samuelson, a Nobel Prize winner in Economics, who has made many contributions to the economic literature, wrote an article for a newspaper in 1973, stating that military spending would no longer be necessary for economic growth and employment. Because according to Samuelson, Keynesian economists now know how to deal with these problems (Toporowski, 2016: 439). However, the rise of Keynesianism, which was on the rise in the post-war period and gained a respectable place academically, economically and politically, did not last much longer. In 1973, there was a contraction in oil production and as a result, crude oil prices rose. In a short period of time, the level of employment was also affected by this contraction. Another important result was the emergence of stagflation, which affected the US in a short time and reduced productivity (Krugman, 2016: 121). The Keynesian understanding of economics was seen as responsible6 for this crisis in 1973 and was subjected to serious criticism, especially from monetarists (Veggeland, 2018).

5. Climate Crisis, Inequalities and Military Spending

The problem of climate change is becoming more and more evident as a major threat to the world. The solution to this problem requires global cooperation of all countries. Governments should reprioritize their resources to combat climate change. In recent years, countries have taken this problem more seriously and started to take various steps. However, the onset of the Covid-19 pandemic and the ensuing Ukraine-Russia War have caused this problem to take a back seat again. In particular, the Ukraine-Russia War caused military expenditures to increase again7, especially in Western countries, and the war replaced diplomacy in a way that Keynes would not approve of (Toporowski, 2023). Military spending is not only inefficient, as noted earlier, but also highly harmful to the climate due to the military industry’s dependence on fossil fuels (Pereira et al., 2022: 3). As Nakano (2021) points out, it is also doubtful that military spending in a neoliberal economy will lead to a more egalitarian and democratic society as it did in World War II. Military spending is therefore a form of public spending that is considered problematic in green new deal (GND) plans. In order to tackle climate change, among other challenges, they argue that military spending should be cut in addition to other resources. However, how much this cut should be is relative and varies depending on the plan. Pollin and Chomsky’s Climate Crisis and the Global Green New Deal states that at least 6 % of global military spending should be allocated to combating climate change (Chomsky & Pollin, 2020). Jeremy Rifkin (2019), in his GND plan for the US, states that the US military budget is excessively large compared to other countries. According to Rifkin, the US is investing in weapons that it may never use. For this reason, Rifkin argues that according to 2019 figures, 30 billion dollars from the US military budget should be transferred to the GND.

There are also those who argue that the above-mentioned approaches are not radical enough and that there should be a more radical cut in military spending. For example, according to the approach advocated by Max Ajl (2022), military expenditures cause developed countries to establish hegemony over less developed countries. On the other hand, military expenditures cause massive carbon emissions and pollution, which is another problematic situation. Therefore, military spending should be completely halted in developed countries such as the United States, and the resources that saved should be used to reduce climate change and global inequalities. Another radical proposal is made by Peter Custers (2010b). Custers argues that there should be a transition from military spending to ecology-oriented public investments. However, this transition will not be sufficient for humanity and ecology. Thus, there should be a simultaneous transition from non-productive to productive investments. Although these ideas may seem plausible in the current climate crisis, it is also predicted that governments will not easily give up these expenditures, given the risks in the geopolitical arena and the interests of the military-industrial complex (Goldstein & Tyfield, 2018: 86). Many empirical studies also show that resources that should be used in sectors such as education and health are used for military expenditures and that there is a trade-off between security and social expenditures (Elveren, 2019). Military expenditures may be beneficial in terms of employment, social solidarity and equality in the short run. However, in today’s neoliberal economic conditions, it erodes social solidarity and equality (Nakano, 2021). From a social Keynesian perspective, it is necessary to invest in civilian expenditures instead of military expenditures, as suggested by Keynes. Since one of the main objectives of the GNDs is to reduce inequalities and achieve full employment, these expenditures would be compatible with the GND (Harris, 2013).

6. Conclusion

Military expenditures are a component of public expenditures and, just like other public expenditures, they increase aggregate demand and generate the multiplier effect. Military expenditures are considered to have many positive aspects as they bring waste resources into production, increase employment and contribute to the development of new technologies. On the other hand, military expenditures are also subject to serious criticism. These criticisms include the fact that public expenditures lead to consequences such as war and violence, the transfer of resources and skilled labor to the military sphere that could be used in the civilian sphere, the fact that military expenditures lose their ability to increase aggregate demand in the long run and that they do not provide the necessary technological benefits in the long run. Military spending is called military Keynesianism because it increases aggregate demand and provides new employment opportunities. Although military spending resembles Keynesianism in terms of its outcomes, Keynesianism is about more than increasing aggregate demand and employment. Keynesianism is pro-labor, democratic and egalitarian. This means that the New Deal, which has Keynesian elements and consists almost entirely of civilian spending, is actually more in line with the Keynesian definition. The Keynesian definition of military spending, which causes war and violence, would not be in line with Keynesian thinking. As an economist who emphasized peace and diplomacy, Keynes also emphasized civilian expenditures rather than military expenditures in increasing aggregate demand. According to Keynes, war and violence are phenomena that endanger civilization. Indeed, the human tragedies and ecological destruction caused by wars today vindicate Keynes. Therefore, in order to solve climate change, income inequality and other problems, global military expenditures should be reduced and used in areas such as the environment, education and health. Such civilian expenditures would be more aligned with Keynes’s vision as they would generate positive results in terms of aggregate demand and employment.


1 Ph.D., Independent Researcher metindogan6216@gmail.com, ORCID: 0000-0002-5832-7212.

2 It is also called military Keynesianism in the literature due to the relationship between military expenditures and aggregate demand and employment. Source: Dunne, 2013: 113.

3 Mazzucato states that government investments, especially in financially risky areas, will provide more profitable investments for the private sector in the future. After World War II, he argues that technologies such as the internet and GPS, which emerged thanks to military expenditures, started to be used in the civilian sphere, and companies such as Apple and Microsoft gained an advantage in the global competitive environment. Source: Mazzucato, 2021.

4 Since military expenditures have a multiplier effect and increase aggregate demand, they can pull the economy out of stagnation and provide economic expansion. Source: Dunne, 2014: 119.

5 In the 20th century, there have been many developments in civilian expenditures in many industrialized countries, notably in the UK and Germany. The state became increasingly interventionist in areas such as education, health and employment. Source: Chang, 2015.

6 Nakano finds it wrong to blame Keynesianism for the 1973 crisis. The crisis was triggered by the US involvement in the Vietnam and Israel wars during this period. Source: Nakano, 2021.

7 Global military expenditures exceeded 2 trillion dollars in total for the first time. In this environment of high military spending, new military tensions emerge every year Source: SIPRI, 2022.

References

  • Ajl, M. (2022). Halkın Yeşil Yeni Düzeni, Polen Ekoloji Kitaplığı. İstanbul: Ceylan Yayınları.
  • Baca, G. (2021). Neoliberalism’s Prologue: Keynesianism, Myths of Class Compromises and the Restoration of Class Power. Anthropological Theory. https://doi.org/10.1177/1463499621989130
  • Barker, T. (2019). Macroeconomic Consequences of Peace: American Radical Economists and the Problem of Military Keynesianism, 1938–1975. Research in the History of Economic Thought and Methodology, V:37A, Emerald. https://doi.org/10.1108/S0743-41542019000037A004
  • Caslin, T. (1993). Devlet ve Ekonomi. In K. Saybaşılı (Ed.), Liberalizm, Refah Devleti, Eleştiriler. İstanbul: Bağlam Yayınları.
  • Chang, H. J. (2015). Kalkınma Reçetelerinin Gerçek Yüzü. İstanbul: İletişim Yayınları.
  • Chomsky, N., & Pollin R. (2020). The Climate Crisis and the Global Green New Deal: The Political Economy of Saving the Planet. London; New York: Verso Books.
  • Coulomb, F., & Alcouffe, A. (2018). Economic Interventionism, Armament Industries and the Keynesian Theory: The economists debates in France and Great Britain, 1936–1940. ESHET
  • Custers, P. (2010a). The Tasks of Keynesianism Today: Green New Deals as Transition Towards a Zero Growth Economy?. New Political Science, 32(2), 173–191.
  • Custers, P. (2010b). Military Keynesianism Today: An Innovative Discourse. Race & Class, 51(4), 79–94. https://doi.org/10.1177/0306396810363049
  • Cypher, J. M. (2015). The Origins and Evolution of Military Keynesianism in the United States. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 38(3), 449–476.
  • Dunne, J. P. (2013). Military Keynesianism: An assessment. Contributions to Conflict Management, Peace Economics and Development, Vol. 20 Part 2 (pp. 117–129). Emerald.
  • Dunne, J. P. (2014). Military Keynesianism: An Assessment. In Cooperation for a Peaceful and Sustainable World Part 2. Published online: 16 Sep 2014, pp. 117–129.
  • Elveren, A. Y. (2019). Askeri Harcamalar ve Ekonomi: Eleştirel Bir Yaklaşım. İstanbul: İletişim.
  • Field, A. J. (2009). The Great Depression, the New Deal, and the Current Crisis. Challenge, 52(4), 94–105. https://www.jstor.org/stable/40722591
  • Goldstein, J., & Tyfield, D. (2018). Green Keynesianism: Bringing the Entrepreneurial State Back in(to Question)?. Science as Culture, 27(1), 74–97, https://doi.org/10.1080/09505431.2017.1346598
  • Harris, J. (2013). Green Keynesianism: Beyond Standard Growth Paradigms. Global Development and Environment Institute (Working Paper No. 13-02), ss. 1–19.
  • Keynes, J. M. (1933). An Open Letter to President Roosevelt. The New York Times. https://www.nytimes.com/1933/12/31/archives/from-keynes-to-roosevelt-our-recovery-plan-assayed-the-british.html
  • Keynes, J. M. (2010). İstihdam, Faiz ve Paranın Genel Teorisi. İstanbul: Kalkedon Yay.
  • Krugman, P. (2016), Bir Liberalin Vicdanı, Literatür yayıncılık, İstanbul
  • Mauro, P., Romeu, R., Binder, A., & Zaman, A. (2015). A Modern History of Fiscal Prudence and Profligacy. Journal of Monetary Economics, 76, 55–70. https://ourworldindata.org/government-spending, Accessed on: 19 Ağustos 2021.
  • Mazzucato, M. (2021). Girişimci Devlet: Kamu Sektörü-Özel Sektör Karşıtlığı Masalının Çürütülmesi. İstanbul: Koç Üniversitesi Yayınları.
  • Nakano, T. (2021). War and Strange Non-Death of Neoliberalism: The Military Foundations of Modern Economic Ideologies. International Relations, 35(2), 236–255. https://doi.org/10.1177/0047117820978273
  • Pattifor. A. (2019). The Case for the Green New Deal. Verso Book
  • Pereira, P., Basic, F., Bogunovic, I., & Barcelo, D. (2022). Russian-Ukrainian War Impacts the Total Environment. Science of the Total Environment, 837. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.scitotenv.2022.155865
  • Renshaw, P. (1999). Was There a Keynesian Economy in the USA between 1933 and 1945?. Journal of Contemporary History, SAGE Publications, 34(3), 337–364.
  • Rifkin, J. (2019). The Green New Deal: Why The Fossil Fuel Civilization Will Collapse by 2028, and The Bold Economic Plan to Save Life on Earth. New York: St. Martin’s Press.
  • SIPRI. (2022). World Military Expenditure Passes $2 Trillion for First Time. https://www.sipri.org/media/press-release/2022/world-military-expenditure-passes-2-trillion-first-time, Accessed on: 9 April 2023
  • Stancl, L., & Hynkova, V. (2014). Origin and Development of the Thoughts on Military Keynesianism During 1936–2012. AARMS, 13(1), 131–139.
  • Toporowski, J. (2016). Multilateralism and Military Keynesianism: Completing the Analysis. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 39(4), 437–443.
  • Toporowski, J. (2023). The War in Ukraine and the Revival of Military Keynesianism. Institute for New Economic Thinking. https://www.ineteconomics.org/perspectives/blog/the-war-in-ukraine-and-the-revival-of-military-keynesianism, Accessed on: 9 April 2023.
  • Veggeland, N. (2018). Economic Crises: A Keynesian New Deal Perspective. In Keynesian Policies A New Deal in the European Narrative: Employment, Equality and Sustainability (pp. 81–11).
  • White, L. (2012). The Great Depression and Keynes’s General Theory. In The Clash of Economic Ideas: The Great Policy Debates and Experiments of the Last Hundred Years. Cambridge.
  • Wray, L. R. (2000). Can Penal Keynesianism Replace Military Keynesianism? Available at SSRN: http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1010343

Details

Pages
490
Year
2023
ISBN (PDF)
9783631902547
ISBN (ePUB)
9783631912546
ISBN (Softcover)
9783631902554
DOI
10.3726/b21515
Language
English
Publication date
2023 (November)
Keywords
Public Finance Business Economics Panel Data Analysis Time Series Analysis
Published
Berlin, Bern, Bruxelles, New York, Oxford, Warszawa, Wien, 2023. 490 pp., 22 fig. b/w, 75 tables.

Biographical notes

Adil Akinci (Volume editor)

Adil Akıncı works at Bilecik S¸eyh Edebali University as an Associate Professor. He currently teaches fiscal policy and public finance–related subjects in Turkey. His field of interest comprises public expenditure, public revenue and time series analysis.

Previous

Title: Interdisciplinary Public Finance, Business and Economics Studies—Volume VI